Skip to main content
Log in

The emergence of unshared consensus decisions in bottlenose dolphins

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Behavioral Ecology and Sociobiology Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Unshared consensus decision-making processes, in which one or a small number of individuals make the decision for the rest of a group, are rarely documented. However, this mechanism can be beneficial for all group members when one individual has greater knowledge about the benefits of the decision than other group members. Such decisions are reached during certain activity shifts within the population of bottlenose dolphins residing in Doubtful Sound, New Zealand. Behavioral signals are performed by one individual and seem to precipitate shifts in the behavior of the entire group: males perform side flops and initiate traveling bouts while females perform upside-down lobtails and terminate traveling bouts. However, these signals are not observed at all activity shifts. We find that, while side flops were performed by males that have greater knowledge than other male group members, this was not the case for females performing upside-down lobtails. The reason for this could have been that a generally high knowledge about the optimal timing of travel terminations rendered it less important which individual female made the decision.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Altmann J (1974) Observational study of behaviour: sampling methods. Behaviour 49:227–267

    Article  PubMed  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Ay N, Flack JC, Krakauer DC (2007) Robustness and complexity co-constructed in multimodal signalling networks. Philos Trans R Soc Lond B 362:441–447

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baird RW, Dill LM (1996) Ecological and social determinants of group size in transient killer whales. Behav Ecol 7:408–416

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barclay (1982) Interindividual use of echolocation calls: eavesdropping by bats. Behav Ecol Sociobiol 10:271–275

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blundell GM, Ben-David M, Bowyer RT (2002) Sociality in river otters: cooperative foraging or reproductive strategies? Behav Ecol 13:134–141

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boisseau OJ (2004) The acoustic behaviour of resident bottlenose dolphins in Fiordland, New Zealand. Department of Marine Sciences, University of Otago, Dunedin, p 320

    Google Scholar 

  • Boisseau OJ (2005) Quantifying the acoustic repertoire of a population: the vocalizations of free-ranging bottlenose dolphins in Fiordland, New Zealand. J Acoust Soc Am 117:2318–2329

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Boyko AR, Gibson RM, Lucas JR (2004) How predation risk affects the temporal dynamics of avian leks: greater sage grouse versus golden eagles. Am Nat 163:154–165

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Bradbury JW, Vehrencamp SL (2000) Economic models of animal communication. Anim Behav 59:259–268

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Cairns JS, Schwager SJ (1987) A comparison of association indices. Anim Behav 35:1454–1469

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Connor RC, Heithaus MR, Barre LM (2001) Complex social structure, alliance stability and mating access in a bottlenose dolphin ‘super-alliance’. Proc R Soc Lond B 268:263–267

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Conradt L, Roper TJ (2000) Activity synchrony and social cohesion: a fission–fusion model. Proc R Soc Lond B-Biol Sci 267:2213–2218

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Conradt L, Roper TJ (2003) Group decision-making in animals. Nature 421:155–158

    Article  PubMed  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Conradt L, Roper TJ (2005) Consensus decision making in animals. Trends Ecol Evol 20:449–456

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Couzin ID, Krause J, Franks NR, Levin SA (2005) Effective leadership and decision-making in animal groups on the move. Nature 433:513–516

    Article  PubMed  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Currey RJC, Dawson SM, Slooten E (2007) New abundance estimates suggest Doubtful Sound bottlenose dolphins are declining. Pacific Conservation Biology 13:265–273

    Google Scholar 

  • Dawson SM (1991) Clicks and communication: the behavioural and social contexts of Hector's dolphin vocalizations. Ethology 88:265–276

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eguiluz VM, Zimmermann MG, Cela-Conde CJ, San Miguel M (2005) Cooperation and emergence of role differentiation in the dynamics of social networks. Am J Soc 110:977–1008

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Flack JC, Girvan M, de Waal FBM, Krakauer DC (2006) Policing stabilizes construction of social niches in primates. Nature 439:426–429

    Article  PubMed  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Fritz H, de Garine Wichatitsky M (1996) Foraging in a social antelope: effects of group size on foraging choices and resource perception in impala. J Anim Ecol 65:736–742

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Götz T, Verfuss UK, Schnitzler HU (2006) ‘Eavesdropping’ in wild rough-toothed dolphins (Steno bredanensis)? Biol Lett 2:5–7

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Heard DC (1992) The effect of wolf predation and snow cover on musk-ox group-size. Am Nat 139:190–204

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jakob EM (2004) Individual decisions and group dynamics: why pholcid spiders join and leave groups. Anim Behav 68:9–20

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krause J, Lusseau D, James R (2009) Animal social networks: an introduction. Behav Ecol Sociobiol. doi:10.1007/s00265-009-0747-0

  • List C (2004) Democracy in animal groups: a political science perspective. Trends Ecol Evol 19:168–169

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Lusseau D (2003) Male and female bottlenose dolphins Tursiops sp. have different strategies to avoid interactions with tour boats in Doubtful Sound, New Zealand. Mar Ecol-Prog Ser 257:267–274

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lusseau D (2006) Why do dolphins jump? Interpreting the behavioural repertoire of bottlenose dolphins (Tursiops sp.) in Doubtful Sound, New Zealand. Behav Processes 73:257–265

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Lusseau D (2007a) Evidence for social role in a dolphin social network. Evol Ecol 21:351–366

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lusseau D (2007b) Why are male social relationships complex in the Doubtful Sound bottlenose dolphin population? PLoS ONE 2:e348

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Lusseau D, Higham JES (2004) Managing the impacts of dolphin-based tourism through the definition of critical habitats: the case of bottlenose dolphins (Tursiops spp.) in Doubtful Sound, New Zealand. Tour Manage 25:657–667

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lusseau D, Newman MEJ (2004) Identifying the role that animals play in their social networks. Proc R Soc Lond B 271:S477–S481

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lusseau D, Schneider K, Boisseau OJ, Haase P, Slooten E, Dawson SM (2003) The bottlenose dolphin community of Doubtful Sound features a large proportion of long-lasting associations—can geographic isolation explain this unique trait? Behav Ecol Sociobiol 54:396–405

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lusseau D, Williams RJ, Wilson B, Grellier K, Barton TR, Hammond PS, Thompson PM (2004) Parallel influence of climate on the behaviour of Pacific killer whales and Atlantic bottlenose dolphins. Ecol Lett 7:1068–1076

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lusseau D, Whitehead H, Gero S (2008) Incorporating uncertainty into the study of animal social networks. Anim Behav 75:1809–1815

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lusseau SM, Wing SR (2006) Importance of local production versus pelagic subsidies in the diet of an isolated population of bottlenose dolphins Tursiops sp. Mar Ecol Prog Ser 321:283–293

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Mann J (2000) Unraveling the dynamics of social life: long-term studies and observational methods. In: Mann J, Connor RC, Tyack PL, Whitehead H (eds) Cetacean societies. University of Chicago Press, London, pp 45–64

    Google Scholar 

  • Monni S, Li HZ (2008) Vertex clustering in random graphs via reversible jump Markov chain Monte Carlo. J Comput Graph Stat 17:388–409

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Newman MEJ (2003) The structure and function of complex networks. SIAM Review 45:167–256

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Newman MEJ (2004) Fast algorithm for detecting community structure in networks. Phys Rev E 69:066133

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Newman MEJ (2006a) Finding community structure in networks using eigenvectors of matrices. Physics Review E 74 (2006), p. 036104

    Google Scholar 

  • Newman MEJ (2006a) Modularity and community structure in networks. Proc Nat Acad Sci USA 103:8577–8582

    Article  PubMed  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Newman MEJ, Girvan M (2004) Finding and evaluating community structure in networks. Phys Rev E 69:art026113

    Google Scholar 

  • Noe R, Bshary R (1997) The formation of red colobus-diana monkey associations under predation pressure from chimpanzees. Proc R Soc Lond B-Biol Sci 264:253–259

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Norris KS (1994) The Hawaiian spinner dolphin. University of California Press, Berkeley

    Google Scholar 

  • Quinn GP, Keough MJ (2002) Experimental design and data analysis for biologists. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK

    Google Scholar 

  • Rodgers KL, Wing SR (2008) Spatial structure and movement of blue cod in Doubtful Sound, New Zealand, inferred from delta C-13 and delta N-15. Mar Ecol Prog Ser 359:239–248

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rosvall M, Bergstrom CT (2007) An information-theoretic framework for resolving community structure in complex networks. Proc Nat Acad Sci USA 104:7327–7331

    Article  PubMed  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Ruckstuhl KE (1999) To synchronise or not to synchronise: a dilemma for young bighorn males. Behaviour 136:805–818

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ruckstuhl KE, Neuhaus P (2002) Sexual segregation in ungulates: a comparative test of three hypotheses. Biol Rev Camb Philos Soc 77:77–96

    PubMed  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Schneider K (1999) Behaviour and ecology of bottlenose dolphins in Doubtful Sound, Fiordland, New Zealand. Marine Sciences, University of Otago, Dunedin, p 200

    Google Scholar 

  • Seppänen J-T, Forsman J-T, Mönkkönen M, Thomson RL (2007) Social information use is a process across time, space and ecology, reaching heterospecifics. Ecology 88:1622–1633

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Templeton JJ, Giraldeau LA (1996) Vicarious sampling: the use of personal and public information by starlings foraging in a simple patchy environment. Behav Ecol Sociobiol 38:105–114

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Whitehead H (2009) SOCPROG programs: analyzing animal social structures. Behav Ecol Sociobiol. doi:10.1007/s00265-008-0697-y

  • Whitehead H, Dufault S (1999) Techniques for analyzing vertebrate social structure using identified individuals: review and recommendations. Adv Study Behav 28:33–74

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Williams JA, Dawson SM, Slooten E (1993) The abundance and distribution of bottle-nosed dolphins (Tursiops truncatus) in Doubtful Sound, New Zealand. Can J Zool 71:2080–2088

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Würsig B, Würsig M (1977) The photographic determination of group size, composition, and stability of coastal porpoises (Tursiops truncatus). Science 198:755–756

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yamagiwa J, Kahekwa J, Basabose AK (2003) Intra-specific variation in social organization of gorillas: implications for their social evolution. Primates 44:359–369

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

DL was supported by a Killam Postdoctoral fellowship provided by the Killam Trusts. LC is supported by a Royal Society University Research fellowship. We would like to thank Hal Whitehead for numerous fruitful discussions and suggestions, Shane Gero for suggestions on earlier drafts, and three anonymous reviewers. Data collection and compilation was funded by the New Zealand Whale and Dolphin Trust, the New Zealand Department of Conservation, Real Journeys Ltd, and the University of Otago (Departments of Zoology and Marine Sciences and Bridging Grant scheme). We would also like to thank Susan M. Lusseau, Oliver J. Boisseau, Liz Slooten, and Steve Dawson for their numerous contributions to this research.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to David Lusseau.

Additional information

Communicated by J. Krause

This contribution is part of the special issue “Social Networks: new perspectives” (Guest Editors: J. Krause, D. Lusseau and R. James).

Appendix 1. Contextual knowledge and its influence on the emergence of unshared consensus decisions

Appendix 1. Contextual knowledge and its influence on the emergence of unshared consensus decisions

The following model is based on the Condorcet jury theorem. Its purpose is to show that, if the level of information is generally high within the group, any increase in information of the group member with the highest reach (in relative and in absolute terms) adds relatively little advantage to an unshared decision. On the other hand, if the level of information is generally low within the group, already a small difference in information between the highest reach member and other group members might make an unshared decision more profitable than a shared decision. This could explain the different observations in decisions about the initiation and about the termination of traveling bouts, if these two types of decisions are accompanied by different general levels of relevant information within the group.

We assume that the animal with the highest reach in a school has the probability, p r, to get the decision about timing of traveling right (i.e., to time it optimally given their energy budget) and the probability 1−p r to get it wrong (i.e., time the traveling not optimal). Furthermore, we assume that all other group members, which have lower reach, have a lower probability p s (p s < p r) to get the decision right, if they made the decision individually. Thus, the median probability to get the decision right of all individuals is p s (assuming group size is larger than two). This median probability p s is, thus, a measure of ‘the general level of information within the group’.

We rewrite p r as:

$$ p_{\text{r}} = p_{\text{s}} + \lambda \times \left( {1 - p_{\text{s}} } \right), $$
(5)

with 0 < λ ≤ 1 (since p r > p s, and p r is bounded at 1).

Hence,

$$ p_{\text{r}} - p_{\text{s}} = \lambda \times \left( {1 - p_{\text{s}} } \right) $$
(6)

where λ is a measure of the difference in information between the most informed group member and the other members.The probability that a school would make a right decision if it followed the SF (or ULT, respectively) signal of the animal with highest reach would be p r (unshared consensus decision). The probability that a school would make a right decision if it decided democratically (assuming for reasons of simplicity that school size n is uneven) would be:

$$ p_r \cdot \sum\limits_{{i = \frac{n - 1}{2}}}^{n - 1} {\left( {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {n - 1} \\ i \\ \end{array} } \right)} \cdot p_s^i \cdot \left( {1 - p_s } \right)^{n - 1 - i} + (1 - p_r ) \cdot \sum\limits_{{i = \frac{n + 1}{2}}}^{n - 1} {\left( {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {n - 1} \\ i \\ \end{array} } \right)} \cdot p_s^i \cdot \left( {1 - p_s } \right)^{n - 1 - i} $$
(7)

Thus, a school would make a better decision by following the most knowledgeable individual, if:

$$p_{\text{r}} > p_{\text{r}} \cdot \sum\limits_{{i = \frac{n - 1}{2}}}^{n - 1} {\left( {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {n - 1} \\ i \\ \end{array} } \right)} \cdot p_{\text{s}}^i \cdot \left( {1 - p_{\text{s}} } \right)^{n - 1 - i} + (1 - p_{\text{r}} ) \cdot \sum\limits_{{i = \frac{n + 1}{2}}}^{n - 1} {\left( {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {n - 1} \\ i \\ \end{array} } \right)} \cdot p_{\text{s}}^i \cdot \left( {1 - p_{\text{s}} } \right)^{n - 1 - i}$$
(8)

and the difference between an unshared and a shared consensus decision (diffdesp-dem) in terms of probability to make the right decision would be:

$$ \begin{array}{*{20}c} {{\text{diff}}_{{{\text{desp - dem}}}} = p_{r} - p_{r} \cdot \sum\limits_{{i = \frac{{n - 1}}{2}}}^{{n - 1}} {\left( {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {n - 1} \\ i \\ \end{array} } \right)} \cdot p_{s}^{i} } \\ { \cdot \left( {1 - p_{s} } \right)^{{n - 1 - i}} - \left( {1 - p_{r} } \right)} \\ { \cdot \sum\limits_{{i = \frac{{n + 1}}{2}}}^{{n - 1}} {\left( {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {n - 1} \\ i \\ \end{array} } \right) \cdot p_{s}^{i} \cdot \left( {1 - p_{s} } \right)^{{n - 1 - i}} } } \\ \end{array}$$
(9)
$$ \begin{gathered} = p_{\text{r}} - p_{\text{r}} \cdot \sum\limits_{{i = \frac{n - 1}{2}}}^{{\frac{n - 1}{2}}} {\left( {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {n - 1} \\ i \\ \end{array} } \right)} \cdot p_{\text{s}}^i \cdot \left( {1 - p_{\text{s}} } \right)^{n - 1 - i} + p_{\text{r}} \cdot \sum\limits_{{i = \frac{n - 1}{2} + 1}}^{n - 1} {\left( {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {n - 1} \\ i \\ \end{array} } \right)} \cdot p_{\text{s}}^i \cdot \left( {1 - p_{\text{s}} } \right)^{n - 1 - i} \hfill \\ - \left( {1 - p_{\text{r}} } \right) \cdot \sum\limits_{{i = \frac{n + 1}{2}}}^{n - 1} {\left( {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {n - 1} \\ i \\ \end{array} } \right)} \cdot p_{\text{s}}^i \cdot \left( {1 - p_{\text{s}} } \right)^{n - 1 - i} \hfill \\ \end{gathered} $$
(10)
$$ \begin{array}{*{20}c} { = p_{r} \cdot \left[ {1 - \frac{{\left( {n - 1} \right)!}}{{\left( {\frac{{n - 1}}{2}!} \right)}} \cdot p_{s}^{{\frac{{n - 1}}{2}}} \cdot \left( {1 - p_{s} } \right)^{{\frac{{n - 1}}{2}}} } \right]} \\ { - \sum\limits_{{i = \frac{{n + 1}}{2}}}^{{n - 1}} {\left( {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {n - 1} \\ i \\ \end{array} } \right) \cdot p_{s}^{i} \cdot \left( {1 - p_{s} } \right)^{{n - 1 - i}} } } \\ \end{array}$$
(11)
$$ \begin{array}{*{20}c} { = \left( {p_{s} + \lambda \cdot \left( {1 - p_{s} } \right)} \right)} \\ { \cdot \left[ {1 - \frac{{\left( {n - 1} \right)!}}{{\left( {\frac{{n - 1}}{2}!} \right)^{2} }} \cdot p_{s}^{{\frac{{n - 1}}{2}}} \cdot \left( {1 - p_{s} } \right)^{{\frac{{n - 1}}{2}}} } \right]} \\ { - \sum\limits_{{i = \frac{{n + 1}}{2}}}^{{n - 1}} {\left( {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {n - 1} \\ i \\ \end{array} } \right) \cdot p_{s}^{i} \cdot \left( {1 - p_{s} } \right)^{{n - 1 - i}} } } \\ \end{array}$$
(12)

Since diffdesp-dem is the difference between an unshared and a shared decision with respect to the probability of getting the decision right, it is a measure of the relative advantage of an unshared over a shared decision.

From Eq. 12, it follows that diffdesp-dem is correlated with the difference in information between the most informed group member and the other members (λ) as follows:

$$ \frac{{\partial {\text{diff}}_{{{\text{desp}} - {\text{dem}}}} }}{{\partial \lambda }} = \left( {1 - p_{\text{s}} } \right) \cdot \left[ {1 - \frac{{\left( {n - 1} \right)!}}{{\left( {\frac{n - 1}{2}!} \right)^2 }} \cdot p_{\text{s}}^{{\frac{n - 1}{2}}} \cdot (1 - p_{\text{s}} )^{{\frac{n - 1}{2}}} } \right] $$
(13)

That is, the advantage of an unshared versus a shared decision increases with the information discrepancy λ with a slope given by Eq. 13. The size of this slope is always positive but decreases with p s (Fig. 3). That means the larger the general level knowledge of all group members within the group (i.e., p s), the less advantage (i.e., diffdesp-dem) does an increase in superior information of the member with the highest reach (i.e., λ) convey in an unshared decision and vice versa.

Fig. 3
figure 3

The relationship between the median knowledge of members of the schools (p s , i.e., excluding the individual with the maximum knowledge), school size, and \( \frac{{\partial {\text{diff}}_{{{\text{desp}} - {\text{dem}}}} }}{{\partial \lambda }} \) which is the difference in correctness to take an unshared consensus decision as opposed to a shared consensus one (diffdesp-dem) given the discrepancy in knowledge between the most knowledgeable and others in the schools (λ). See “Appendix 1” for derivation

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Lusseau, D., Conradt, L. The emergence of unshared consensus decisions in bottlenose dolphins. Behav Ecol Sociobiol 63, 1067–1077 (2009). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00265-009-0740-7

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Revised:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00265-009-0740-7

Keywords

Navigation